PDF Summary:The Bitcoin Standard, by Saifedean Ammous
Book Summary: Learn the key points in minutes.
Below is a preview of the Shortform book summary of The Bitcoin Standard by Saifedean Ammous. Read the full comprehensive summary at Shortform.
1-Page PDF Summary of The Bitcoin Standard
In The Bitcoin Standard, economics professor Saifedean Ammous suggests that bitcoin has the potential to become a new international monetary standard, similar to the gold standard of the 1800s. But the Bitcoin Standard would be superior to the gold standard in a number of ways because the properties of bitcoin make it—at least potentially—a superior form of money to gold, while also solving many of the problems with the fiat currencies that countries have been using since they got off the gold standard. In this guide, we’ll describe Ammous’s vision for a global Bitcoin Standard and look at how close we might be to implementing it. We’ll also compare Ammous’s perspective to that of other thinkers, such as Edward Griffin and Milton Friedman.
(continued)...
In principle, if too many countries prohibit bitcoin, the remaining network might become so concentrated in one or a few countries that its decentralized structure would be compromised. If those countries then passed laws requiring those operating bitcoin servers to implement new protocols, they could control the supply or other facets of bitcoin.
And in any case, Ammous’s vision for a bitcoin Standard isn’t likely to become a reality unless a majority of governments come to embrace it. Right now, some countries, like the US, may be moving slowly in that direction. But others, such as China, are clearly moving away from it.
Why Bitcoin Makes Good Money
Now that we’ve discussed how bitcoin avoids the problems fiat money poses, let’s examine how bitcoin is generally a good form of money and has the potential to become the new monetary standard.
Ammous explains that there are two properties that determine how suitable something is for use as money: ‘salability’ and ‘hardness.’ Then there’s the issue of trust in the payer: The form of money can influence the likelihood of a transaction failing due to nonpayment. We’ll discuss each of these factors in turn to show why Ammous thinks bitcoin makes good money.
Bitcoin Has Good Salability
As Ammous uses the term, ‘salability’ is the ability of something to transmit value. He says there are three dimensions to salability: scale, space, and time.
Scale-Salability
The scale-salability of something is its ability to transmit value between purchases of different size. For example, maybe you sell something of great value, like a house, and then you want to use a little bit of the money from the sale to purchase something of small value, like a loaf of bread. The scale-salability of something that is used as money depends mostly on how easily divisible it is into units of different value.
Bitcoins have excellent scale-salability because they’re easily divisible in practice: The bitcoin network supports transactions as small as 0.00000001 bitcoin. So you could sell a house for 25 bitcoins and buy a loaf of bread for 0.00015 bitcoins without any trouble.
Scalability Makes Bitcoin Succeed Where Gold Failed
In Capitalism and Freedom, Milton Friedman observes that during the globalization of the economy, precious-metal money became untenable because there wasn’t enough of it to cover all transactions. Equivalently, we could say that precious metals didn’t have adequate scale-salability, because, in theory, any quantity of sufficiently valuable money would be adequate for the global economy if it was infinitely divisible.
For example, you could sell a house for 250 ounces of gold, but you couldn’t easily buy a loaf of bread for 0.0015 ounces of gold, because this quantity of gold is too small to easily measure or keep track of. A gold coin weighing 0.0015 ounces would only be one eighth of an inch in diameter (comparable to the size of the letter “o” at normal printed text sizes) and as thick as a human hair. But bitcoin’s greater divisibility overcomes this problem.
Space-Salability
The space-salability of something is its ability to transmit value over geographical distances. For example, maybe you want to sell a house in New York and buy one in Colorado. If your buyer offered to pay in either gold or cattle (both of which Ammous notes have historically been used as money), it would be much easier to carry 250 gold coins with you across the country than to transport 250 head of cattle. As such, gold has much better space-salability than cattle.
Bitcoins have excellent space-salability because they only exist as entries in a digital ledger, which is stored redundantly on many “nodes” throughout the world and accessed via the internet. So you can access your bitcoins from anywhere in the world, provided you can connect to the internet.
(Shortform note: Some economists argue that bitcoin has too much space-salability. For example, in A Random Walk Down Wall Street, Burton Malkiel opines that bitcoin is an ideal medium in which to carry out illegal transactions because bitcoin facilitates easy, anonymous, irreversible transactions without respect to national boundaries. As such, he conjectures that sooner or later, most governments around the world will take steps to shut down the bitcoin network as a means of fighting crime, after which the value of bitcoins will drop to zero. He thus advises against investing in bitcoin, as he sees its current value as a bubble that will eventually break.)
Time-Salability
The time-salability of something is its ability to transmit value across time. For example, maybe you want to save up for a big purchase over a period of years or decades. Ammous warns that if you try to save up your money in dollars or other fiat currency, your savings will lose value over time due to inflation.
At present, bitcoin’s time-salability is not as good as its scale-salability or space-salability because its value fluctuates unpredictably. Ammous discusses several factors that contribute to bitcoin’s volatile price.
For one thing, bitcoins exist only as a digital currency, whereas many other things that have been used as money have commercial uses that give them tangible value to begin with. For example, the price of gold never drops below a certain threshold because of the commercial demand for gold to be used in making jewelry and certain electrical components. Bitcoins don’t have this basic commercial value, so their value can fluctuate more erratically.
For another thing, the price of bitcoin is the only factor that can adjust to match supply with demand because the supply of bitcoin at any given time is fixed. By contrast, both supply and price are variable for most other goods. When the demand for a commodity rises, driving up prices, the higher prices motivate producers to increase production. This increase in supply helps to balance out the increased demand, so the price doesn’t rise as much.
So too, if the demand for a commodity drops, prices start to drop, and suppliers cut back on production. But because the supply of bitcoin is fixed, its price fluctuations can’t be ameliorated by increases or decreases in supply, so its price will fluctuate more dramatically in response to fluctuations in demand.
Ammous observes that the effect of demand fluctuations is amplified by the relatively small market for bitcoins and by the temperament of the people who hold them: Many bitcoin holders tend to buy or sell large quantities of bitcoin, depending on whether they think the price will go up or down. This results in proportionately larger fluctuations in demand for bitcoin relative to other currencies and commodities.
However, Ammous also contends that this could change. If the bitcoin market continues to grow, demand may become less volatile. And if central banks build stockpiles of bitcoin to back other currencies (which is an important step toward adopting a Bitcoin Standard) this would also tend to stabilize the value of bitcoins.
Will the Value of Bitcoin Ever Stabilize?
Economists differ on the question of whether or not it’s even hypothetically possible to stabilize the value of bitcoin, let alone whether or not its value will eventually stabilize in practice.
Experts argue that the supply and demand issues Ammous references are part of a larger ecosystem of influences that affect bitcoin’s value at any given time. Media hype and government intervention are two other significant drivers of bitcoin volatility. They observe that when bitcoin makes the news in a positive way (such as an announcement that a prestigious securities trading firm will now begin trading in bitcoins) the price of bitcoin tends to skyrocket.
Conversely, when bitcoin makes the news in a negative way, or especially in a way that could raise concerns about its future availability or legality (such as a news story about the government shutting down a bitcoin-based business for engaging in illegal activities, or a government announcing prohibitions on the use of bitcoin by its citizens) the price of bitcoin tends to plummet.
Ammous would probably point out that regulatory concerns and media hype are simply factors that influence demand. If these are indeed the primary factors behind its volatility, then this volatility will likely diminish with time: Eventually, governments will settle on their cryptocurrency policies, reducing concerns about bitcoin’s legality or regulatory status changing. And the more bitcoin matures, the less media hype it’s likely to generate.
But others contend that bitcoin’s strictly limited supply makes it fundamentally unstable, arguing that the price volatility of bitcoin cannot be eliminated without a mechanism to regulate the money supply of bitcoins the way central banks regulate the supply of fiat currencies. One university team proposed creating an alternative cryptocurrency that would operate similarly to bitcoin, but with an additional algorithm built into the code to monitor exchange rates and adjust the supply of the cryptocurrency to keep the exchange rates consistent.
Others have created other cryptocurrencies and attempted to stabilize their value by backing the cryptocurrency with either fiat currency reserves such as US dollars, physical commodities such as gold or real estate, or financial securities, such as stocks.
Ammous would probably be skeptical of these solutions. As we’ve discussed, he is concerned that fiat money has poor time-salability because of inflation. So cryptocurrencies that are backed by fiat currency or whose supply is adjusted to maintain a consistent exchange rate with them would suffer from the same problem and lose one of bitcoin’s significant advantages. Similarly, a cryptocurrency backed by commodities or financial securities would be only as stable as what it was backed by. Moreover, it would require a trusted central entity to hold the reserves. But, as we’ve discussed, the decentralized structure of bitcoin that obviates the need for a trusted third party is another one of its significant advantages.
Bitcoin Is Hard Money
As we’ve discussed, bitcoin’s time-salability isn’t ideal because bitcoin’s value tends to fluctuate, but Ammous asserts that despite these short-term fluctuations, bitcoin does have good time-salability in the long run because it is a very “hard” currency, and thus does not lose value due to inflation. In this section we’ll discuss the “hardness” of money, which is another factor that, along with salability, determines how good a type of money is.
Ammous explains that the “hardness” of a type of money is the ratio of the total quantity in circulation to the maximum amount that could be added in a given amount of time, usually one year.
For example, wheat has a very low hardness, because it is produced and consumed every year, and so the total supply is about the same as the annual production. By contrast, gold has a very high hardness, because it is relatively scarce and humans have been stockpiling it for thousands of years, so the amount of gold produced by gold mines in any given year is only a tiny fraction of the world’s total gold supply.
Bitcoin is designed such that bitcoins are added to circulation at a predictable rate that is halved every four years, and will cease altogether once the total number in circulation reaches 21,000,000 bitcoins. Thus, bitcoin has a high hardness, and that hardness will continue to increase until all the bitcoins are in circulation, at which point its hardness will become infinite.
(Shortform note: As of 2022, over 90% of the 21,000,000 total bitcoins are already in circulation, and the rate of growth is about 328,500 bitcoins per year, or 1.7% per year. For comparison, the world supply of gold is about 200,000 tons, and global gold production is about 3,200 tons per year, or 1.6%, so bitcoin already has comparable “hardness” to gold.)
Hard Money Prevents Inflation From Redistributing Wealth
Ammous demonstrates the importance of hard money by observing what happens to a society that uses money with low hardness: Over time, all the real value in that society goes to those who provide the supply of money.
As Ammous explains, this is because there’s always a demand for any material that a society uses as money (such as gold or silver), which motivates people to produce it (for example, by mining gold). Yet, increasing the money supply decreases the value of the money that’s already in circulation.
It takes time for the economy to adjust to changes in the value of money, so when producers of money (such as gold miners) sell their product, they receive more payment for it than it will be worth once the economy adjusts to the increased money supply. This is what allows the producers of money to accumulate a greater and greater fraction of society’s real wealth over time.
If the society uses hard money, such as gold or bitcoin, the magnitude of this effect is small. But it gets larger the faster the money supply increases. For example, if the money supply abruptly doubles, then the value of money will be cut in half, so the people who increased the supply will acquire half of the total value that the money supply represented before it doubled.
Production of Money and Redistribution of Wealth
In Capitalism and Freedom, Milton Friedman makes a case that forced redistribution of wealth within a society is unjust. This principle adds weight to Ammous’s concerns about money losing its purchasing power because, as Ammous explains, expanding the money supply effectively results in redistribution of wealth.
Friedman argues that all ethical commerce is based on the principle of voluntary exchange. People buy, sell, and trade with each other because of inequalities in resources and abilities that make it mutually beneficial for them to do business with each other. Any involuntary exchange or any redistribution of wealth that benefits some people at the expense of others is morally wrong. He insists that this is the case whether the redistribution takes the form of a band of robbers stealing from a person at gunpoint or a majority of voters enacting laws that collect money from a wealthy minority and distribute it to the less affluent.
In light of Ammous’s exposition of how increases in the money supply redistribute purchasing power, it seems Friedman would also have to condemn any actions taken to expand the money supply as immoral. This is because, as we’ve seen, creating new money effectively redistributes purchasing power from everyone who uses the currency to those who produce the currency. And it does this involuntarily through the process of inflation.
If expanding the money supply is immoral, then Friedman would likely feel that any moral society would naturally favor hard money, since it severely limits anyone’s ability to expand the money supply.
Bitcoin Is Based on Verification Instead of Trust
Ammous asserts that the final desirable characteristic of bitcoin is its system of complete verification, which eliminates the need for trust.
He explains that many other types of transactions require a degree of trust: If someone writes you a check, you’ll only accept it as payment if you trust that their check won’t bounce. If someone pays you with a credit card, the credit card company acts as a trusted third party, verifying her credit and guaranteeing payment of her debts. But that means the credit card company can block any transaction that it disapproves of, even if the payer and the payee both approve of it. But with bitcoin, there’s no need to trust either the payer or a third party because of its system of complete verification.
Complete verification means that the network first checks to make sure the payer can make the payment (they have sufficient funds in their account) and then irreversibly transfers the funds, ensuring that the payer does make the payment. Furthermore, these checks are performed not just by a single payment processor, but by a majority of the network—a large number of independently-operated servers all over the world. To default on a payment or make a fraudulent payment, the payer would have to gain control of a majority of the entire bitcoin network, which, as we’ve discussed, would be virtually impossible. This is how the network ensures that the payer can’t default, eliminating the need for trust.
Ammous points out that this is ideal for settlements between parties located in different countries, who might have limited options for enforcing an agreement to pay. It also means that all bitcoin transactions are final, irreversible, and immune to third-party stipulations, much like paying someone in cash or gold.
But, as Ammous concedes, this approach also creates a large amount of redundancy (relative to using a trusted third party like a credit card company) since each transaction is independently verified by a majority of the entire network, not just a single server. This redundancy reduces the efficiency and speed of processing transactions.
The Barbell Model and the Tradeoff Between Safety and Efficiency
The tradeoff between efficiency and safety isn’t unique to bitcoin, but rather is a principle that applies broadly to finance and life in general. Every action that you can take, whether it’s making an investment, launching a business venture, traveling on vacation, or something else carries a certain amount of risk—or, equivalently, a certain amount of trust. Trust and risk are closely related because most risks boil down to someone or something failing to perform the way you trusted that they would. In almost every case, there are ways of mitigating the risk, but they come at a cost.
For example, if you’re investing in stocks, you can reduce your risk of losing money by diversifying your portfolio. This works because it’s much less likely that many companies will fail or lose value at once than that a single company’s stock price will plummet. But it also reduces your potential to profit, because it’s also much less likely that all your stocks will grow exponentially than that just one of them will.
Bitcoin’s network works in a similar manner by having each transaction verified by many different nodes all over the world. It’s possible that one person operating a node or even a cluster of nodes would try to falsify a transaction, but it’s virtually impossible to get a majority of nodes on the entire network to approve it.
There are many possible strategies for managing the tradeoff between risk or safety and efficiency or profit. In Antifragile, Nassim Taleb recommends using the “barbell” model, where you organize all your assets, projects, and so forth into two groups: a high-risk group and a low-risk group (with the two groups kept at a distance from each other, like the weights on either end of a barbell). For example, you might invest 80% of your savings in low-risk securities like treasury bonds and term certificates, while you invest the other 20% in high-risk stocks.
What the Bitcoin Standard Doesn’t Look Like
We’ve discussed the properties of bitcoin that arguably make it an ideal form of money and allow it to solve some of the problems with common fiat currencies. And we’ve laid out Ammous’s vision for a global bitcoin standard in which banks use bitcoin as an international reserve currency, much like they once used gold. But if bitcoin is a superior form of money, why would only banks use it for settling their debts? Why wouldn’t we all just switch to using bitcoins directly? Ammous explains that there are two reasons bitcoin will never be a global currency for day-to-day transactions.
First, as digital transactions go, bitcoin is slow. It takes about 10 minutes for a bitcoin transaction to clear. If you’re running a grocery store and have people in line to check out, you can’t wait 10 minutes for each payment to go through.
Second, bitcoin can’t handle a high enough volume of sales. The bitcoin network can only handle about half a million bitcoin transactions per day. That’s enough to cover large balance settlements between banks throughout the world, but not enough to cover all commercial transactions: A single major credit card company may need to process hundreds of millions of transactions per day.
These limitations are inherent in the design of bitcoin, so scaling up the bitcoin network as more people adopt cryptocurrency won’t appreciably increase the transaction speed or the number of transactions that can be completed per day.
Making Bitcoin Faster
There are a number of possible solutions to increase the number of bitcoin transactions that can take place in a given amount of time. One solution would be to change how the payment processing network operates for the purpose of making it more efficient and increasing the volume of transactions it can handle. Various people and organizations have developed other cryptocurrencies along these lines that compete with bitcoin, but so far, none of them have successfully challenged bitcoin’s market share.
For example, “bitcoin cash” is a cryptocurrency that is closely based on bitcoin, but with larger “blocks” (meaning that more transactions can be added to the ledger at a time) and slightly relaxed security features. The bitcoin cash network should be able to process roughly a hundred times more transactions per day than the bitcoin network, but the time for an individual transaction to clear wouldn’t necessarily be any shorter. Thus far, “bitcoin cash” isn’t catching on: Due to lesser demand, units of “bitcoin cash” are worth less than a hundredth as much as bitcoins.
Another alternative is to add a second layer of transaction processing to the bitcoin network, so that parties who are willing to trust each other can bundle all their transactions over a period of time into a single net transaction on the network. This is what the bitcoin Lightning Network does. In theory, the Lightning Network has the potential to make most bitcoin transactions almost instantaneous, and the number of possible transactions per day almost infinite. It remains to be seen whether it will ever be adopted on a large scale and work well enough in practice to provide a good solution.
Want to learn the rest of The Bitcoin Standard in 21 minutes?
Unlock the full book summary of The Bitcoin Standard by signing up for Shortform.
Shortform summaries help you learn 10x faster by:
- Being 100% comprehensive: you learn the most important points in the book
- Cutting out the fluff: you don't spend your time wondering what the author's point is.
- Interactive exercises: apply the book's ideas to your own life with our educators' guidance.
Here's a preview of the rest of Shortform's The Bitcoin Standard PDF summary:
What Our Readers Say
This is the best summary of The Bitcoin Standard I've ever read. I learned all the main points in just 20 minutes.
Learn more about our summaries →Why are Shortform Summaries the Best?
We're the most efficient way to learn the most useful ideas from a book.
Cuts Out the Fluff
Ever feel a book rambles on, giving anecdotes that aren't useful? Often get frustrated by an author who doesn't get to the point?
We cut out the fluff, keeping only the most useful examples and ideas. We also re-organize books for clarity, putting the most important principles first, so you can learn faster.
Always Comprehensive
Other summaries give you just a highlight of some of the ideas in a book. We find these too vague to be satisfying.
At Shortform, we want to cover every point worth knowing in the book. Learn nuances, key examples, and critical details on how to apply the ideas.
3 Different Levels of Detail
You want different levels of detail at different times. That's why every book is summarized in three lengths:
1) Paragraph to get the gist
2) 1-page summary, to get the main takeaways
3) Full comprehensive summary and analysis, containing every useful point and example